The Governmental Regulation vs. Litigation Spectrum
There’s a pretty great ongoing conversation going on below stemming from a comment-turned-post by Jaybird on the unintended costs of governmental regulations. As always, my thoughts on the subject of governmental regulation don’t lean toward “Yay Government Oversight!” or “Boo Government Oversight!” but rather where do we agree that it is needed, and to what extent?
That being said, I want to chime in and say that even those in the blogosphere that discuss the hidden costs of governmental regulations usually ignore the expenses that proportionally rise as regulation falls: the costs associated with liability indemnification.
We have a tendency to think that in industrialized countries governmental intervention either exists and costs go up, or it doesn’t and costs go down. But in a democratic society there are always two competing mechanisms to ensure against corporate malfeasance: government oversight, and litigation. These two mechanisms exist on opposite sides of a seesaw; as the costs associated with one increase, the costs associated with the other decrease.
At my company we might have a client that has manufacturing operations in both the States and in Europe. The costs associated with adhering to governmental regulations – fees, taxes, man-hours, etc. – are significantly higher in Europe. Not only do they have greater oversight, but also in most European countries if you cut corners and produce a food product that killed scores of people, the government has the ability to come down hard on you. Overly negligent actions by a corporation in the United States might lead to someone being fired and the company fined; in Europe it might well mean prosecution and jail time.
However, the overall costs are not as different as you might think. This is because in the States we use another tool to regulate corporate malfeasance: litigation. The amount that you can successfully sue a corporation for is stratospherically higher here than in most other industrial countries, and this creates huge cost differences on the risk transfer side. If you process meat in Fordhall, England your product liability costs are dwarfed by the costs of you doing the same in Provo, Utah.
So if you save money in one country by not having to go through so much red tape, you generally turn around and pay that savings to your insurance company (or, if you are large enough to self-insure, your re-insurance company). Third world countries, of course, usually choose neither oversight nor a litigious system. Instead, by choosing neither they choose to live with corporate malfeasance.
But if you agree that corporate malfeasance should be discouraged, you can have a society of governmental oversight, or you can have society that is very litigious – or you can pick the place on the spectrum between them where you are most comfortable. But the idea that simply reducing governmental oversight directly reduces your costs is not that simple.
Is regulation for preventing the bad or to enhance the good as well? This is where one’s political philosophy comes in, about regulation’s essential purpose.
Of course some regulations are necessary: people cheat. The question is whether we impose regulation with regret, or with gusto.Report
I don’t think that question matters. We still get fire escapes, regardless of whether you’re fuming mad that an entire building of people burned to ashes, or whether you’re “regretting” the extra expense of fire escapes on all buildings in america.Report
Sticking with preventing the bad is generally the best idea, IMO.
Regulation that enhances the good is much less likely to be effective, and much more likely to have unintended consequences.
It’s a lot like “targeted tax cuts”, that way.Report
Obligatory “Reference-that-no-one-but-me-and-like-five-other-people-will-even-get” starts… now:
This question reminds me of the book Witches Abroad by Terry Pratchett. In the fairytale city of Genua, the evil ruler makes a series of regulations designed to make the city happier. So all innkeepers must by fat and jolly, and toy makers must tell stories to the children and whistle all the live long day. There is a hysterical yet chilling scene where a toy maker who doesn’t know any stories and can’t whistle – but knows how to makes toys – is brought up on charges, convicted, and sent off to be tortured.Report
The stories problem you could solve by just getting the guy high, the double-rainbow dude is pretty funny to children.
Not much you can do about the whistling, though. Torture is probably the only option.Report
Nice post, T-dog.Report
In the very early days of railroads, a RR could pick and choose what they customers they would serve and who they would not. It did not take long in such a case for every biz in a town that was served by one RR to all be owned by the RR. This was immensely profitable for RR but crippled the overall economy by restricting competition. This lead to the ‘common carrier’ regulation that said RR must accept the same cargo from all people who wanted to ship and must charge the same price for shipping the same cargo to all people. This meant RR were no longer maximizing their potential profitability but the economy as whole was better off.
(if you think this example is old history then you have not been paying attention to what the people who control the fiber on the internet have been trying to do)
The entire history of this country, including the very libertarian 19th century, has been about the govt laying out the ground rules in an industry and then letting companies compete. Sometimes done right, most often a very corrupt activity but always it has been this way. To think this will change is to engage in Utopian thinking.
What we can do is try to make the process less corrupt. Regulation should be about what we want to make utility, to be provided as close to cost as we can, vs what we want to let the market fight over.
Make no mistake, regulation will always be used to pick winners or losers unless you believe in Utopian fantasies i.e. THIS TIME WILL BE DIFFERENT.Report
How did common-carrier legislation “pick winners or losers”?Report
Common-Carrier itself doesn’t, but regulation in general can be used to pick winners & losers, usually by raising the barrier to entry so high as to prevent smaller competitors from getting a foothold in an established market (see the CPSIA, or Jaybirds example of needing permission for other nearby businesses to open a business).
We should also note that probably 95% of anti-business regulations are local, not federal. The bad thing about federal regulation is that it raises the barrier everywhere, whereas local regulations just choke out new business in small areas.Report
When the doctrinaire Republican right has finished with us, there will be no more balance between regulation and litigation. Litigation for product liability (or malpractice, for that matter) will be outlawed. The only ones subject to litigation will be you and I, for failure to pay up whatever the unregulated banks demand of us.
Yours very crankily,
The New York CrankReport
Remember that oversight will also (more likely) prevent the tragedy from occuring while litigation only compensates for the result. An ounce of prevention and all that.Report
This is a great reminder that non-regulations can result in many of the same things that actual regulations lead to.
This is why I have a problem with Ron Paul’s position on pollution, i.e. battle it out in the courts over property damage claims.
One, that ends up being retroactive instead of preventative. Yes, it will incentivize people not to pollute, i.e. damage other people’s property, but we know that humans aren’t always rational. And once the damage is done, it’s done.
Second, this results in cost shifting rather than cost controlling. A lot of libertarian/free market reforms seem to be that way. There are plenty of genuinely efficient and reasonable ones, but plenty of others as well that simply shift costs around rather than actually decrease or get rid of them all together.Report
… also remember that it incentivizes people to pollute a little. enough that it’s not provable in court, even if the trout die. You’ll still have muskies, right?Report
“We have a tendency to think that in industrialized countries governmental intervention either exists and costs go up, or it doesn’t and costs go down. But in a democratic society there are always two competing mechanisms to ensure against corporate malfeasance: government oversight, and litigation. These two mechanisms exist on opposite sides of a seesaw; as the costs associated with one increase, the costs associated with the other decrease”
In a perfect democracy of just people, we’d have a one-to-one trade-off. Arguably, having the government bear the majority of the cost is the more egalitarian way to hedge against corporate malfeasance. But this is a false dichotomy: we have a system in the United States that manages to incorporate both a regulatory structure that often encourages malfeasance if it is not the agent of malfeasance itself and a legal system that is not worth its cost and that generally serves anti-egalitarian purposes.Report
CC, can you explain?Report
For example: safety, IP, and zoning regulations benefit established players and cartels. We discussed this a lot on my and Jaybird’s posts over the weekend. At the same time, the poor have the drug war and incompetent public defenders to deal with, among other things.
We actually have policies that redistribute in the opposite direction, and we have a lot of them.Report
There’s also the mental mistake of thinking that without government regulation there would be no regulation. I haven’t read all the comments, so if someone brilliant has beat me to this brilliant point, I apologize. And before someone brings up Upton Sinclair and the Jungle, my point is more nuanced and up-to-date.Report
An excellent point.Report